Ideal policies to promote renewable energy development in the EU
are not yet in place. The Renewables Directive was only agreed
after many compromises and national interests might blunt its
effect. It is, however, a significant achievement.
In practice, policymaking rarely, if ever, conforms
to the rational ideal. One of the many reasons
for this is that there are often competing
rationalities that make it difficult or even
impossible to identify what the 'ideal' would
be. Different actors with competing objectives
have contrasting views. What is good for society
at large need not be good for each of the individual
actors within that society. Although in
theory governments should act on behalf of the
wider public interest, in many instances if they
wish to adopt new policies they must either
confront or compensate those actors that benefit
from the status quo.
Even when there are a relatively small number
of competing interests, policymaking necessarily
involves contestation and compromise and
the nature of these compromises depends on the
relative power of the winners and losers. When
the definite costs of change are imposed on
actors who are powerful in the here and now,
while the prospective benefits will be secured
by actors who might become powerful in the
future, there is an in-built bias towards the status
quo. In the case of environmental policy
there is the extra issue that while many of the
costs associated with environmental policy are
relatively easy to measure in monetary terms,
many of the diffuse and often rather intangible
social and environmental benefits are not easily
monetised.
A second reason for departures from the ideal is
that governments commonly operate under conditions
of 'bounded rationality'. When surveying
the options that are open to them, they
rarely have the time, the resources or the expertise
needed to conduct a comprehensive analysis
of the numerous ways with which they could
achieve their objectives. Instead, they have to
muddle through, often taking satisfactory rather
than optimal decisions. Furthermore, when
deciding how to progress, they very rarely start
with a blank sheet of paper. Instead, they normally
inherit various habits and traditions, as
well as the institutions that emerged to support
previous policies. Because decision makers are
often risk-averse, they may stick with an
approach that has worked (or at least not failed)
in the past instead of trying to adopt something
that might be better but that also might fail. As
a result, many of the more radical opportunities
that could only work if policy-makers were able
to create new institutions and if they took a risk
are commonly overlooked. Instead, policy tends
to evolve gradually, often through a series of
small and frustratingly slow steps.
A third reason is that while some issues can be
addressed within a single sphere of policy,
many issues can only be addressed through a
complex multi-sectoral and multi-level
approach that is inherently difficult to coordinate.
The need for a multi-sectoral approach is
particularly evident in the environmental field
as environmental policymakers are commonly
required to respond to the negative after effects
of other policies (c.f. agriculture, transport etc.).
Joined-up thinking is therefore required; but
this would require increased environmental
awareness and a change of culture across the
different spheres of government.
Fourthly, despite the focus on governments
making policy, it is probably more accurate to
say that while policies are designed by governments,
they are not really made until they are
interpreted and applied by implementing agencies.
Particularly in the context of the EU where
subsidiarity is such an important principle, this
means that all of the organisations and individuals
that are involved in the transposition,
implementation and enforcement processes are
able to influence the practical substance of policy.
These actors may or may not subscribe to
the central objectives of the policy in question,
and even if they do they have a considerable
amount of discretionary room for manoeuvre.
Furthermore, there is an obvious and critically
important role for local and national inputs to
the policy process. Bottom-up approaches to
policy development with all of the diversity that
they bring are at least as important as top-down
approaches, and as a consequence harmonisation
on paper does not necessarily equate to harmonisation
in practice.
Finally, many policies have a long shelf life,
information on their performance is often
scarce and the opportunities for policy learning
are commonly limited. Ex-post evaluations of
policy performance are quite difficult to conduct,
not least because it is difficult to isolate
the influence of the policy in question from that
of the wide range of other factors that combine
to shape behaviour or performance on the
ground. As a result, sub-optimal policies often
remain in place for some time, especially if they
are not so much failing as mildly under-performing.
The maxim of if it's not broke, don't
fix it is as true for policy-makers with limited
time and attention as it is for everyone else.
To compound these problems, there are real
questions about the ability of government to
influence technological change processes. Two
contrasting viewpoints are significant here. One
very economic perspective is that if governments
and markets get the costs and benefits
right, rational and responsive actors will quickly
change their behaviour to suit. The other
more institutional perspective suggests that
actors are nowhere near as responsive as the
economic perspective implies. Instead, they are
deeply embedded in existing trajectories, and
while there may be moments when they are
open to influence, for long periods they are
actually quite resistant to change.
More fundamentally, the institutional perspective
suggests that technological change processes
are unpredictable and often unmanageable.
Instead of being omnipotent, therefore, governments
are often confined to a role where they
can only react to the technological changes
brought about, for example, through globalisation.
As a result, in many instances governments
can exert only a marginal rather than a
defining influence on the pace or the direction
of technological change.
Again the reasons for such observations are
manifold. However, two or three theoretical
observations can help us to understand the reasons
why technological processes may be
resistant to government influence.
Firstly, the right conditions have to be in place
if policy is to trigger an innovative response. As
in every market, successful outcomes only8
emerge where the supply of new technologies is
matched by demand for those technologies. The
supply of innovation is dependent upon the
technological opportunities, market structure
and the ability of the innovator to appropriate a
proportion of the benefits associated with the
innovation (see Dosi, 1988). Similarly, the
demand for innovation is dependent upon the
price and quality of the innovation, the transfer
of knowledge and information relating to an
innovation and the perceptions of economic risk
and uncertainty associated with the application
of that innovation (see Kemp and Soete, 1992).
In order for supply to meet demand, we need
networks that facilitate the transfer of information
and understanding between the actors at
various stages of the innovation process. Where
information flows freely, interactive learning
between actors at different stages can facilitate
a cumulative and self-reinforcing process of
innovation. The consequence of this is that systems
that have been innovative in the past are
more likely to be innovative in the future. While
this can be good for some sectors or regions, it
can be very difficult to encourage technological
change in contexts that have not been innovative
in the past. Overcoming this threshold can
require substantial and sustained investment.
Secondly, new innovations depend upon a system
or network of relations without which their
adoption would be impossible. The introduction
of a new innovation into one part of an existing
system may require changes to be made to other
parts of the system. Considerable resistance and
inertia may be apparent in this respect. For
example, firms (and indeed sectors, regions and
countries) that have successfully mastered the
operation of old technologies and techniques
commonly face difficulties in acquiring the new
skills and knowledge needed to successfully
apply new technologies and techniques (OECD,
1992). Consequently, innovations that require
only incremental change to existing systems are
more likely to be adopted than those that
require more radical change. As a result, change
becomes path-dependent and significant barriers
to radical change emerge even where there
is both a supply of raw technologies and a latent
demand for them.
Thirdly, there is an inherent paradox that lies at
the heart of the technological change process:
in their early stages, new technologies will not
be adopted because they are costly to produce
and risky to use, but the only way in which their
costs of production and the risks of their adoption
fall is if they are more widely adopted
(OECD, 1992). However, where initial reluctance
can be overcome, there can be increasing
returns to adoption (see Kemp, 1993; Soete and
Arundel, 1995). On the supply-side, the diffusion
of a new technology is normally associated
with improvements in its quality as experience
with its production accumulates and reductions
in its cost as economies of scale are exploited.
On the demand side, as the innovation is adopted,
users learn to apply it more efficiently and
effectively and establish or adapt an appropriate
system to surround the innovation. Over time
therefore, the cost of the innovation drops and
the quality increases. Furthermore, the information
and knowledge gathered by actual users
can be transferred to potential users so that the
risks of adoption decrease. An increased community
of users can also facilitate joint problem
solving, cumulative learning and the establishment
of a supporting infrastructure. In combination,
these factors mean that first-movers
need to be encouraged to adopt new technologies
as second and third movers will then benefit
from lower costs, reduced risk and higher
quality.
Thus, we can see that if new technologies are to
be adopted, the right conditions have to be in
place on the ground and the incentives have to
be strong enough to overcome initial inertia.
These factors become more and more significant where the technologies to be adopted are
radically different from their predecessors.
However, as has been established, as policy
makers may not be in a position to put the best
policy framework in place to enable this to happen,
significant barriers to change may remain.
In view of all this, if someone were to design
the optimal policy framework to promote the
development and diffusion of renewable energy
technologies, what would it look like? Within
the EU there are clearly different perspectives,
and policy must be developed and enacted at
levels ranging from the EU to the local.
However, in theory at least, most would agree
that an optimal policy framework would
include some common components:
1) Where they needed to intervene, policy makers
could do so safe in the knowledge that the
competitive implications of their interventions
would be minimal as their major competitors
would adopt similar goals.
2) There would be ready access to investment
resources at both the macro- and the micro-levels
that would allow any short-term costs to be
more than offset by medium-term benefits. The
overall level of the benefits would also be
enough to compensate any losers whilst still
leaving society as a whole better off.
3) There would be a broad and stable consensus
amongst different actors and at different levels
(EU, member state, regional, local) both on the
ultimate objectives for policy and on the ways
in which these would be achieved. Unambiguous goals would be clearly communicated
to give consistent and predictable longterm
signals to the market place.
4) There would be an integrated or joined-up
approach that spanned the boundaries between
different areas of policy. Policies in areas as
diverse as energy, environment, agriculture,
transport, tax and competition would all be
pulling in the same direction.
5) Different policy instruments would be
applied which would both encourage and
enable change. These instruments, which would
include mandatory targets, economic instruments,
information-based approaches, capacity
building measures and support for basic R&D,
would be applied in concert within a complementary
policy mix.
6) There would be perfect implementation so
that the range of policies and instruments
adopted were applied as intended at the national,
regional and local levels.
7) There would be enough flexibility in the system
to allow implementing agencies to take into
account the variable conditions encountered by
different technologies and by diverse actors
operating in contexts that change over time and
space.
8) Markets would serve to reinforce government
policies. External costs and benefits
would be internalised so that social and environmental
impacts were accurately reflected in
economic transactions and there would be perfect
information to inform voter and consumer
behaviour.
9) Actors on the ground would understand, support
and have the capacity to respond to the
wide range of signals from government, from
the market and from society at large.
10) Infrastructure would also be flexible
enough to accommodate the needs of new
renewable energy technologies.
Even a basic understanding of the political realities
of life in the EU, as well as of the administrative
contexts within which policies are
made and implemented and of the economic
contexts within which target actors must
respond, suggests that such a 'rational ideal' is
unlikely to be grounded in reality. Of course
this is not to say that policy makers should not
seek to identify the ideal and then work towards
it, merely to point out that in practice there are
lots of barriers to be overcome before this can
happen. In an acknowledgement of these barriers,
more and more commentators are emphasising
the significance of 'multi-level governance'
in the EU, where action depends on not
on the top-down imposition of policy but on
diverse actors at different levels actively 'buying-
in' to the objectives of policy.
Now that we have set up an ideal and explored
the reasons why it may not be realised in practice,
we are in a position to examine the extent
to which EU policies are likely to promote the
further development and diffusion of renewable
energy technologies. While many other policies
also play an important role, two key policy documents
will be assessed here: first, the EU
White Paper for a Community Strategy and
Action Plan on Renewable Energy Sources
which was published in 1997, second, the EU
directive on the Promotion of Electricity
Produced from Renewable Sources which was
adopted in 2001. By examining these policy
documents, the paper will be able to review the
factors shaping the evolution of EU policies on
renewables over the last five years or so. By
examining the European Environment Agency's
report on 'Renewable Energies: Success
Stories' (2001) the paper can also speculate
about the future of EU support for renewables.
In 1996, the European Commission first mooted
its intention to double the contribution that
renewables made to energy generation to 12%
by 2010. As the 'business as normal' scenario
was predicted to lead to renewables growing
from 6% to 7.7% of the market, the
Commission surveyed best practice in the member
states and predicted that if these national
examples of good policy were applied across
the EU, renewables would attain a market share
of 12.5% by 2010. Policy learning and the diffusion
of good practice were therefore built into
the policy process from the start.
The European Commission's initial soundings
led to mixed reactions. The European
Parliament, a range of environmental groups
and the renewables lobby called for higher targets
and more support. However, there was
opposition from some member states, as well as
from some trade associations and conventional
energy generators, who claimed that the targets
were over-ambitious and would be expensive to
meet. Nonetheless, in 1997 the European
Commission proceeded to publish its White
Paper on Renewables that maintained the 12%
target and set out a range of measures that
would need to be adopted if the target was to be
met. Recognising that there was a need for a
'concerted and coordinated effort by the various
players over time', the measures proposed
included:
Again the White Paper received a mixed
response, and the debate rumbled on for nearly
three years before the European Commission
translated the broad statements of intent that
were included in the White Paper into a draft
directive which, if adopted, would introduce
legally binding obligations. In the period
between the publication of the draft directive in
May 2000 and its adoption in October 2001,
some of the proposals were watered down in a
number of ways whilst a number of others were
retained despite some opposition.
Firstly, the binding targets that were originally
proposed by the Commission became merely
'indicative' targets that the member states were
obliged to work towards but that they were not
legally obliged to meet. While the Commission
is obliged to review progress and to consider the
need for mandatory targets after three years,
opposition to such mandatory targets amongst
the member states is likely to remain and
unless the position changes they are unlikely to
be adopted.
Similarly, although the directive initially sought
to harmonise the ways in which the various
member states supported the development of
renewables, these proposals were rejected following
opposition from some countries.
Instead, a diversity of national schemes will
continue to be applied across the EU for a further
five years, although once more the
Commission has the right to review these
schemes and to propose an EU wide scheme if
necessary. However, as with the question of
whether targets should be made mandatory,
there is no guarantee that any future proposals
for harmonised support for renewables will
actually be approved.
Despite some significant opposition, the directive
also established a basis for financial support
to be given to renewables. Although the
Energy and Environment Directorates of the
European Commission clearly saw the need for
financial support to be provided to renewables,
the Competition Directorate of the European
Commission argued for such financial aid to be
phased out as quickly as possible as it distorted
markets. Countering this view, a consortium of
environmental groups argued that:
Thus, provisions within the directive for financial
support for renewables are retained,
although as the ALTENER II scheme offered on
€22 million over a 5 year period, the level of
support is likely be comparatively modest.
Otherwise, the directive also introduced an obligation
for member states to establish mechanisms
that would guarantee the origin of energy
generated through renewables. In the future,
certificates might then be issued which could be
used as the basis for the trading of green electricity
as countries buy or sell certificates
depending on whether they fall short of or
exceed their targets for renewables or their climate-
change obligations. This would incentivise
renewables generation and lead to greater
investment and more efficient outcomes across
the EU. However, there has been some reluctance
to see the EU pioneering this form of marketable
permit as it is seen by some to be
untried and untested.
For the member states, the directive includes a
requirement that they prepare a report on how
they plan to reduce regulatory and other barriers
to renewables and on how they might streamline
planning procedures to allow for quicker
approval of site-applications relating renewables.
Finally, the directive introduces an obligation
for the operators of transmission and distribution
networks to give priority access to
electricity from renewable sources, although
`these provisions are couched in such general
terms that their impact may be limited' (ENDS,
2000).
While the Renewables Directive is not as strong
as was originally proposed, or as ambitious as
the European Parliament, the renewables lobby
or the environmentalists had hoped, it remains a
significant piece of policy. However, it does not
exist in isolation. As the European Environment
Agency points out (EEA, 2001), member states
can do a lot to create the conditions needed to
allow actors on the ground to respond effectively
to the directive. As stated above, within the
Renewables Directive there is an obligation for
the Commission to review these national mechanisms
and to consider the need for an EU-wide
support scheme. The EEA's review of national
'success stories' may therefore offer some
insight into the EU policies of the future.
In seeking to identify those factors which would
allow the successful introduction of renewable
energy technologies, the EEA (2001, p8) states
`no single factor was identified as being of
over-whelming significance. It is the cumulative
benefits of a series of supportive measures
that determine the extent to which a renewable
technology is successfully exploited'. However,
seven essential factors were identified which
help to create an environment within which
renewable energy exploitation can succeed,
namely:
Thus, the EU has adopted a Renewables
Directive that is backed up by a range of national
support mechanisms. Although the directive
is not as strong as was originally proposed or as
ambitious as some groups had hoped, it is leading
to the development and diffusion of new
renewables technologies in some contexts.
Furthermore, although further changes may not
take place for some years, it seems likely that
EU policy will continue to develop, for example
if the various support schemes that have been
successful at the national level are adopted in a
harmonised framework applicable across the
EU.
Having considered the nature of EU policy on
renewables, and examined the reasons why
their design may be sub-optimal and their influence
rather limited, we are now in a position to
return to the ideal policy model to see how it
compares with the real world.
1) Where they needed to intervene, policy makers
could do so secure in the knowledge that the
competitive implications of their interventions
would be minimal as their major competitors
would adopt similar goals.
Clearly this is not yet the case. As with the
Kyoto Protocol, the lack of parallel commitments
from other countries raises the prospect
that in the short-term at least the EU will be put
at a competitive disadvantage if it raises taxes
on conventional energy sources. Consequently,
renewables are put at a relative disadvantage.
2) There would be ready access to investment
resources that would allow action to be taken,
as any short-term costs associated with transition
could be more than offset by the mediumterm
benefits. The level of the social benefits
would be enough to compensate any losers
whilst still leaving society as a whole better off.
Despite some support for renewables, the
amount of money made available through the
EU is really very modest. However, the indicative
targets introduced by the EU suggest that
the renewables market will grow significantly
in future years. Even in the absence of significant
incentives or subsidies from the EU, this is
likely to build support at the national level and
to encourage private sector investment.
3) There would be a broad and stable consensus
both on the ultimate objectives for policy and
on the ways in which these would be achieved.
Unambiguous goals would be clearly communicated
to give consistent and predictable longterm
signals to the market place.
Clearly this has not been realised. Despite some
loose alliances between the Energy and
Environment Directorates of the European
Commission, the European Parliament, some
environmental groups and the renewables
lobby, these actors have not been powerful
enough to prevent policy targets being watered
down. Actors on the ground therefore receive
mixed messages from different sectors of government
and from the market.
4) There would be an integrated or joined-up
approach that spanned the boundaries between
different areas of policy. Policies in areas as
diverse as energy, environment, agriculture,
transport, tax and competition would all be
pulling in the same direction.
As above, there has been only a limited amount
of 'buy-in' from some other sectors, most
notably in fiscal policy and competition, where
policies that contradict the goals for renewables
remain in place.
5) Different policy instruments would be
applied which would both encourage and
enable change. These instruments, which would
include mandatory targets, economic instruments,
information-based approaches, capacity
building measures and support for basic R&D,
would be applied in concert within a complementary
policy mix.
A range of policy instruments have been
applied which should complement each other to
some extent. However, the links between the
different instruments could be better developed
so that the framework as a whole was more
cohesive.
6) There would be perfect implementation so
that the range of policies and instruments
adopted were applied as intended at the EU,
national, regional and local levels.
As the targets set out by the EU Renewables
Directive are only indicative, its success
depends very much on the commitment of the
member states. While the indicative targets will
be taken seriously in some settings, some states
remain less than fully committed to the national
targets whilst others have resisted the adoption
of a harmonised approach, seemingly preferring
to go their own way. Again this means
that the framework could be more
coherent/consistent.
7) There would be enough flexibility in the system
to allow implementing agencies to take into
account the variable conditions encountered by
different technologies and by diverse actors
operating in contexts that change over time and
space.
The Renewables Directive does give some
scope for flexibility as to how the different targets
are to be met at the national level. It also
builds in an obligation for a review of progress
that creates an opportunity for further policy
development at the EU level and policy learning
at the national level in the near future.
8) Market mechanisms would serve to reinforce
government policies. External costs and benefits
would be internalised so that social and
environmental impacts were accurately reflected
in economic transactions and there would be
perfect information to inform voter and consumer
behaviour.
The external costs and benefits of the different
forms of energy generation have yet to be internalised.
This puts renewables at a clear competitive
disadvantage. Furthermore, liberalisation
has meant that the overall market for energy has
become much more competitive. Nonetheless,
market-pull backed up by government support
will probably be sufficient to lead to the commercialisation
of some renewable technologies. As they are more widely adopted, their quality
will improve and their costs will drop.
However, market-pull will be insufficient to
stimulate investments in blue-sky research for
other technologies. Government support to
overcome some of the most important barriers
to innovation therefore remains necessary.
9) Actors on the ground would understand, support
and have the capacity to respond to the
wide range of signals from government, from
the market and from society at large.
Capacities are developing in many settings -
however it is clear that those regions/sectors
that are most likely to be innovative in the
future are those that have been innovative in the
past. In those contexts where there is no history
of innovation relating to renewables, significant
and sustained investments will be necessary not
only in the technologies themselves but also in
the networks that underpin the innovation
process.
10) Infrastructure would also be flexible
enough to accommodate the needs of new
renewable energy technologies.
Despite calls for greater access to the grid, the
infrastructure continues to reflect the fact that it
was designed to meet the needs of large-scale
conventional generators rather than smaller
scale renewables. Grid access therefore remains
a major barrier to the development of renewable
energies.
As a consequence, it is clear that the ideal policies
have yet to be put in place to promote the
wider development and diffusion of renewable
energy sources in the EU. The negotiation and
compromise needed to secure support for the
Renewables Directive from other departments
of the EU and from various member states
meant that the policies departed from the original
ideal in quite a number of ways.
Furthermore, diverse national approaches and
competing interests in the member states mean
that the policies may not be implemented
whole-heartedly or in the intended way. And
finally, conditions on the ground may restrict
the ability of actors to respond to the policies in
the ways that are hoped.
Nonetheless, the Renewables Directive represents
a significant achievement, and with scope
for learning, EU policy design can develop further
over time. Ultimate success depends upon
the member states' capacity and commitment,
both to deliver these policies and to create the
conditions that will allow actors to respond to
them in efficient and effective ways.
Dosi, G. (1988) The nature of the innovative process, In: Technical Change and Economic Theory, pp. 221-237, G. Dosi, C.
Freeman, R. Nelson, G. Silverberg, L. Soete, (Eds). Pinter Publishers, London
European Commission (1997) Energy for the Future: Renewable Sources of Energy - White Paper for a Community Strategy
and Action Plan, COM(97) 599, 26.11.1997.
European Commission (2001) "Directive 2001/77/EC on the Promotion of Electricity Produced from Renewable Energy
Sources in the Internal Electricity Market", Official Journal of the European Communities, L283/33, 27.10.2001.
European Environment Agency (2001) Renewable Energies: success stories, Environmental Issue Report 27, EEA,
Copenhagen.
Kemp, R. (1993) An economic analysis of cleaner technology: theory and evidence, In: Environmental Strategies for
Industry: International Perspectives on Research Needs and Policy Implications, pp. 79-116, K. Fischer and J. Schot, (Eds).
Island Press, Washington.
Kemp, R. and Soete, L. (1992) "The Greening of Technological Progress" Futures, June pp. 437-457
OECD - Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (1992) Technology and the Economy: The Key
Relationship. OECD, Paris.
Soete, L. and Arundel, A. (1995) European innovation policy for environmentally sustainable development: application of a
systems model of technical change, Journal of Public Policy, 2, 2, pp.285-385.
This is one of almost 50
chapters and articles in the 336-page large format book, Before the Wells
Run Dry. Copies of the book are available for £9.95 from Green Books. Continue to Part C of Section Four: The risks of oil supply disruption for the transport sector
THE INFLUENCE OF POLICY ON
TECHNOLOGICAL CHANGE
THE IDEAL POLICY FRAMEWORK
EU POLICIES ON RENEWABLES
In the European Union at present the electricity
market is significantly distorted to the detriment
of renewable energy generators: access to
grids is restricted, excessive transmissions costs
are applied to renewables; there is still no internalisation
of environmental and social costs;
embedded generators do not receive remuneration
for the savings they create. These factors
and the use of nearly 15 billion ECU in direct
subsidies to the conventional generation sector
all contribute a market distortion that continues
to hold back the harnessing of renewable energy
in the European Union (Greenpeace et al,
1999).
CONCLUSIONS: HOW CLOSELY DOES EU
POLICY REFLECT THE IDEAL?
REFERENCES