How have ecotaxes worked in Germany?
Hans Diefenbacher, Volker Teichert and Stefan Welhelmy
The Irish Government has abandoned its plan to reduce the country's greenhouse gas emissions with an ecotax on the carbon content of fossil fuels which was to have been introduced in 2005. In Germany, similar taxes created over 60,000 new jobs but reduced CO2 emissions by less than 1% in the first two years. This indicates that Irish carbon tax rates would have needed to be very steep for the country to avoid paying hefty fines to the EU because it failed to keep within its Kyoto target.
In 2000, Germany released 858 million tonnes of carbon dioxide into the global atmosphere, equivalent to 9.6 tonnes per head of the population1 . This made the Germans slightly less serious polluters than the citizens of most other industrial countries as the OECD average is 10.9 tonnes a head. The British figure was the same as the German one while the Irish one was rather worse, at 11.1 tonnes. But all three countries' per capita emissions were very much higher than those from the developing world which range from 0.1 tonnes in Nepal and Tanzania, through 0.2 tonnes in Bangladesh and 0.7 tonnes in Pakistan to 1.1 tonnes in India and 2.3 tonnes in China.
Humanity's total carbon dioxide emissions currently exceed the absorptive capacity of global eco-systems ('sinks') by at least 50% - and the amount of the excess is rising. If we take the present world population as being around 6.1 billion, the climate-neutral release of CO2 would therefore be less than 2.3 tonnes per head per year. Per capita emissions in Germany and in the rest of the industrialised world are thus more than four times the estimated climate-neutral amount. This figure not only underlines the need for urgent decisive action but also shows that it is the industrialised countries that must take it.
Ecotaxes are one of the most effective measures to speed the crucial transition from finite, climate-changing fuels like oil and coal to renewable, climate-neutral ones. Since their introduction in Germany in 1999, petrol consumption has fallen for the first time in the country's post-war history. Purchases of three- to five-litre cars increased, for example, an illustration of the way that ecotaxes provide incentives for investment in more environmentally-friendly technologies and, in the long run, create competitive advantages.
Nonetheless, many members of the public still have reservations about ecotaxes. Some even reject them. An ideologically-flavoured party-political debate about them is going on in Germany and we have found that the only way to get the participants to change their positions is to provide them with information about the way ecotaxes work and what they are intended to do.
The EU is slowly adopting ecotaxes. Finland introduced the first CO2-tax in the world in 1990, the Netherlands, Norway and Sweden have had ecotaxes since 1991, Denmark began in 1992 and the United Kingdom in 1993. Austria and Belgium have also incorporated ecological elements into their tax systems. What we can learn from the German experience?
1. Ecotaxes: the basics
People have paid taxes and dues to kings and emperors who promised protection from enemy attacks since ancient times. There have been cases of rulers greedy for power squeezing their subjects to such an extent that eventually both prince and people were faced with financial ruin; but also wise governments using their tax systems to finance pioneering social security measures. Eventually, thanks to attempts to develop a 'rational' theory of state finances, the following criteria for an optimal system of taxes and rates have emerged from the search for the royal road between economic efficiency and social justice:4
- The purpose of taxes is to finance the activities of the state. The range and scale of these activities should be freely decided by the parliament and not the other way round: In other words, the duties the state should take on must not be made primarily dependent on the volume of the overall tax intake. Consequently, taxes have to be plentiful and the tax system reasonably flexible and adaptable.
- The tax system must not put arbitrary burdens on the individual citizen. It must therefore be possible to assess someone's liability to tax on an objective basis; tax law must be transparent and drafted in commonly understandable language; and, finally, the assessment base, the tax rate and the payment dates must be known to the taxpayer.
- The tax burden should be spread among
individual citizens according to ethical
criteria. As ideas on what is 'fair' often change
quite rapidly in a given society,5
tax theory
has developed three very general principles in
recent decades:
- The principle of Generality implies that everyone should pay taxes.
- The principle of Equivalency demands that the 'price' paid for the state's activities (i.e. the overall volume of taxes) should correspond to the benefits the citizens derive from them.
- Finally, the principle of Ability means that all citizens are asked to sacrifice, as far as possible, a fair proportion of their opportunities for private consumption, a principle often used to justify progressive income tax rates.
- A fourth criterion is that taxes should be
used to steer the economy in a desirable
direction. The choice of what is to be
taxed and by how muchshould be made
so that economic structures and activities
and the distribution of incomes and
assets develop in accordance with the
government's underlying economic and
social policies.6
A number of approaches
have been developed for use in socially-oriented market economies. They include:
- policies aimed at redistributing wealth via property taxes, estate duties and through progressive income taxation;
- the promotion of asset accumulation through tax rebates for certain types of income such as capital gains;
- policies designed to alter the geographical structure of the economy by influencing the choice of investment locations through differential rates of company taxation and local property tax rates;
- increasing or decreasing the production of certain products through the levying of special excise taxes;
- policies intended to make the economic system more stable by giving tax rebates for investments, taxing speculative share profits or by imposing anti-cyclical levies;
- policies to alter the exchange rate of the domestic currency through differential taxes on foreign and domestic capital gains or through import and export taxes.
These six criteria are non-controversial - it is over their interpretation and practical application in particular circumstances that people fall out.
Ecotaxes: The most important principles
Ecotaxes are nothing special: they are simply taxes intended to achieve an environmental steering effect, just as other taxes are designed to have effects in other areas. They are intended to influence our use of the environment by changing the price that we have to pay for doing so. A great many types of ecotaxes have been designed in the past twenty years but three central features stand out7 :
- Ecotaxes aim to make the consumption of environmental goods more expensive. Through these taxes, the relative structure of prices gets changed and, it is hoped, behaviour detrimental to the environment becomes less attractive. People frequently argue that raising the price of environmental commodities could lead to 'environmental price truth'. However, whether prices including an ecotax really express the 'true' cost is irrelevant for the steering function to have an effect. Even if it is not possible to determine the exact monetary value of a specific environmental commodity such as an endangered species, the direction of the price change is primarily the thing that matters, not the exact amount.
- A tax aimed at raising the price paid to use the environment should be implemented step by step and should lend itself to long-term calculation. This is so that economic agents such as firms can act to reduce or avoid shortages of environmental commodities arising in future as a result of their too rapid consumption now. The changes in economic behaviour that result from the tax will, as a rule, create employment as well as benefitting the environment. or income and corporate tax rates cut by the amount the ecotax brings in.8
2. The main characteristics of the German ecotaxes
Drawing on ideas discussed since the late seventies and early eighties,9 Germany's red-green coalition government introduced a set of ecotaxes on 1 April 1999 designed to make energy and resource consumption more expensive while lowering the cost of labour. The taxes were introduced in five steps: the initial one raised the tax on electricity by 2 Pfennigs/kWh, the tax on mineral oil by 6 Pfennig/litre, the tax on heating oil by 4 Pfennig/litre and the tax on gas by 0.32 Pfennig/litre. (2 Pfennigs is roughly the equivalent of one euro cent.) Then, in three further steps, the tax on mineral oil was raised by 6 Pfennig/litre on 1 January 2000 and again on 1 January 2001 and the tax on electricity went up by 0.5 Pfennig/kWh on the same dates. On 1 January 2002 and again on 1 January 2003, the tax on mineral oil was raised by 3.1 Cent/litre and the tax on electricity by 0.26 Cent/kWh. That is as far as the process had got by Autumn 2003.
Labour costs were cut by reducing pension contributions. By the end of 2002, the new taxes had brought in an extra €39.3 billion, most of which was used to lower the pension contributions from their level of 20.3% of gross wages in March 1999 to 19.1% in January 2002. Employers and employees have shared the 1.2% saving equally. It was not possible to make further reductions in 2002, but without the introduction of the ecotaxes, the contributions rate would by now have reached 21%.
In addition, some of the ecotax revenue, up to €150 million a year, is used to promote renewable energy. This is roughly equivalent to the ecotax taken from renewable energy sources.
One element of the German ecotaxes that comes in for consistent criticism is the exemptions and reductions given to particular sectors. Manufacturing industries and agriculture receive an 80% reduction of their taxes on heating oil, Revenue derived from ecotaxes should not become part of the general budget but should be reserved for specific tasks. Various approaches are under debate here: most ecotax advocates prefer strict 'revenue neutrality' which means that the revenue raised by the ecotax is fully compensated for by tax reductions elsewhere. For example, social security contributions could be lowered natural gas and electricity. Manufacturing firms are only charged the standard rate for the first ¤500 of their oil, gas and electricity taxes; once payments of ecotaxes rise above 120% of the amount saved by the reduction of ancillary labour costs, companies can apply for a full refund from the customs offices. Public rail transport (trains, trams, trolley buses, urban and suspension railways, metros) receives a 50% reduction of the electricity tax, i.e. it pays only 0.5 Cent per kWh. This amounts to an annual loss of ecotax revenue of around &8364;65 million.
Since January 2000, buses, taxis and other forms of short-distance public transport have only paid the mineral oil ecotax at 1.5 Cent/litre for their fuel. Storage heating systems installed before April 1st, 1999 which are only taxed at half the increased rate. Further exemptions to promote efficient technologies and renewable energy sources are also being given - for example, electricity from combined heat and power generation with an efficiency rate of more than 70% is exempt from mineral oil and electricity taxes. Electricity from renewable sources used for on-site production is also exempt.
3. The ecotaxes' effects
The positive effects of the ecological tax reform were highlighted by the Federal Environmental Bureau (Umweltbundesamt) in early 200210 when it stated that by the end of that year, its projections showed that ecotaxes would have reduced CO2 emissions by more than 7 million tonnes while at the same time creating almost 60,000 new jobs. Other researchers 11 were even more positive, saying that between 176,000 and 250,000 new jobs would be created. These figures were based on the assumption that the trade unions would moderate their wage demands by linking any increases in gross pay to changes in prices and productivity.
These widely-differing estimates shows how much macro-economic models depend on political decisions, which, as a rule, do not lend themselves to adequate modelling. Calculations on the employment effects of ecotaxes consequently need to be treated with caution but our own investigations have led us to take a predominantly positive view of the ecotaxes' income-distribution effects.
There is even disagreement over the reduction in CO2 emissions the taxes will bring about. The ecological tax reform movement expects reductions of around 15 million tonnes, twice the official Umweltbundesamt figure. But if we compare this to the target the Federal Government announced in 1992, which envisaged a 25% reduction (250,000 tonne) by 2005 (see figure 3), ecotaxes can only be a first step along the way.
German reunification and the resulting changes in East Germany have substantially helped to cut the country's CO2 emissions since 1990, especially in the early years. During the first half of the 1990s, CO2 emissions fell by 11%; during the following years, the reductions fell at a much slower rate. The overall reduction for the period between 1990 and 2000 was 15%.
4. Suggestions for extending ecotaxes
The environmental movement reserved its strongest criticism of the ecotax programme for the concessions given to energy use in industry and agriculture. This indirect subsidy saved these sectors around €4.6 billion in 2002 and the European Commission has also objected to it. If these concessions are to be kept any longer, they should be reserved for companies that have implemented environmental management according to EMAS and/or DIN EN ISO 14001 improving the somewhat hesitant up-take of these schemes.
We suggest that from 2004 onwards, ecotax revenue should no longer be reserved for stabilising pension fund contributions. Only a third of ecotax-take should be used that way while a further third (around €12 billion) should be used to lower social insurance rates in view of current labour market conditions. The remaining third should be used to promote renewable energy production and energy saving measures. If energy saving was encouraged, taxes on gas and heating oil, which have not been raised since April 1999, could be increased.
Our suggested changes to the ecotax regime would dissolve its revenue neutrality to some extent but the public has not, so far, noticed the positive effects of the tax reform and subsidies for heat insulation measures could increase the taxes' popular acceptance. Friends of the Earth Germany (BUND) has been thinking on similar lines and has suggested that there should be an extra line on all pay slips showing how much money from ecotaxes is refunded to citizens through reduced pension funds contributions.12 It is also necessary to consider how low-income people, especially pensioners and those receiving unemployment benefit, social welfare or educational grants can be compensated for the losses that ecotaxes have caused them.13 This could be arranged through the annual assessment and pay-off procedures.
As we have already noted, ecotaxes would have to be considerably increased to achieve the Federal Government's climate protection target - minus 25% CO2 emissions by 2005 as compared to 1990. As a result, an intense debate is going on about whether and to what extent flexible economic instruments, like emissions trading, should complement ecotaxes.14
The European Union intends to open up opportunities for emissions trading from 2005, starting with an initial 5,000 companies in five sectors - energy, steel, paper, ceramics and building materials.15 Chemical industries and the transport sector are excluded from this regulation. These companies will be obliged to apply to the environmental agencies of their countries for environmental certificates for their CO2 emissions. From 2008 emissions trading will be opened to further companies.
Many German industries are not in favour of emissions trading. It is the view of the Federal Association of German Industry (Bundesverband der Deutschen Industrie - BDI) that setting an upper limit for CO2 emissions would mean an "entry into the European planned economy".16 Nine of Germany's biggest companies - including RWE and Eon, BASF and Bayer and also Dyckerhoff and Thyssen-Krupp - have criticised the European Commission's plans and declared them to be intolerable. The Chemical Industry Association (Verband der Chemischen Industrie VCI) even threatened to relocate energy-intensive production abroad. Their opposition is in contrast to the positive experiences which oil companies like Shell and BP have had with emissions trading.17
Any price increases for heating oil, gas, electricity and petrol due to increased ecotaxes in future must be signalled well ahead - at least up to 2010 - so that citizens and industry can take account of them when making their plans. It would also be good to arrange for price increases only every second year.
5. How sustainable are ecotaxes?
Whenever the effects of an ecotax are discussed, its promoters and detractors operate with widely differing figures especially where the economic benefits such as the effect on the labour market are concerned. Here, the claims run from "jeopardizing thousands of jobs" to "creating several hundred thousand sustainable positions". On top of this, we have the ecological and social aspects of sustainability to consider.
The way in which a particular ecotax affects these three dimensions of sustainability can neither be measured nor calculated accurately even if complex computer models are used. This is because there is a whole host of factors - wage policies, global economic developments, exchange rates, the price of crude oil etc. - which can boost or reduce the effects that are being assessed. It is, however, possible to deduce certain trends, which can subsequently be related to the relevant targets of sustainable development.
In the environmental sector, the targets most improved by ecotaxes are closely linked: "environmentally and socially compatible mobility", "sparing use of non-renewable resources" and "low energy input": According to data released by the Federal Ministry for the Environment, fuel sales in the first half of 2001 were 5% lower than in the first half of 1999, petrol consumption went down by as much as 12% in this period, while the consumption of diesel fell by just 2%.
German railways registered a passenger increase of 2% in 2000 while rail freight grew by 7.9%. The popularity of agencies organising lifts in private cars (Mitfahrzentralen) was significantly higher - they saw a plus of 25% in the first half of 2000. Overall, the effects of ecotaxes in the environmental area must be regarded as positive and in some sub-sectors even as very positive.
The discussion of the effects of ecotaxes on the economy concentrates on two things: growth and the labour market. Different economic models agree that the taxes have only had a marginal influence on economic growth18 and earlier fears that ecotaxes might turn out to be 'job killers' can now be taken as having been refuted. There are, however, no concrete figures yet to show whether ecotaxes in their present form actually function as a 'job booster'.
The third dimension, the social one, is concerned with a "just distribution of incomes and assets". Using a micro-simulation model, the German Institute for Economic Research (Deutsches Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung, DIW) arrived at the view that the ecotaxes had meant that the net income of most households had been reduced. While these losses were small as a proportion of overall household income, low- and medium-income households fared worst. However, since the ecotaxes were only part of a far-reaching package of tax reforms, the DIW was able to conclude that most households' finances had improved.19
Ecotaxes can therefore be judged to have made a positive contribution to all three aspects of sustainability and they would have become much more effective if their design had been more influenced by ecological imperatives than by political and economic ones. Ecotaxes will only have a decisive impact on sustainable development in Germany if they are combined with further instruments like the Eco-Audit and greater support for renewable energy production. Moreover, all players need to realise that the taxes are an essential part of a long-term strategy. We strongly believe that ecotaxes should be continued over the coming years and that they should continue to contribute to a planned, progressive increase in the price of fossil fuel.
Further information about ecotaxes in Germany:
http://www.oeko-steuer.de/ is the website of the Bund Umwelt und Naturschutz Deutschland on eco-taxes. A newsletter on ecotaxes is available.
http://www.foes.de/ is the Homepage of the Förderverein Ökologische Steuerreform, an organization lobbying for ecotaxes. Very comprehensive.
http://de.fc.yahoo.com/o/oekosteuer.html is a collection of short articles from newspapers etc. Regularly up-dated.
http://www.wegmitdieseroekosteuer.de/ is run by the Christian Democratic Party (CDU) which is against ecotaxes.
http://www.bundesfinanzministerium.de/Grundlagen-.734.5237/.htm an assessment of German ecotaxes published in October 2004 by the Ministry of Finance, together with the complete official texts.
http://www.umweltbundesamt.de/uba-info-presse/hintergrund/oekosteuer.pdf A November 2004 ecotax study by the Umweltbundesamt.
http://www.oekosteuer.at/ A site run by ecotax supporters in Austria.
Ecotaxes currently in use in Ireland
Economic Instruments |
Details | Comments |
Charges/fines: | ||
Derelict sites levy | 3 per cent annually of an urban property's market value. | Low coverage. Revenue in 1994 was £21 000, on property worth £0.7 million. |
Litter fines | Not applied very thoroughly. | No information on revenue. |
Plastic bag levy | Introduced in 2002. 15 cent per plastic bag, revenue used for environmental functions. | Seemingly the most popular tax. Over 70% reduction in plastic bag use. |
User charges: | ||
Domestic water and sewerage charges | Abolished in 1997. | High leakage rates, addressed by investment programme. |
Domestic refuse charges | Mainly fixed charge. Some volume-based refuse charges. Costs partially covered. | Very small but strong resistance to bin charges. Local Authorities and Combat Poverty want Departmental guidance on waiver schemes. |
Non-domestic water, solid waste and waste water: | Volume-based charges wide- spread for water and solid waste, less so for waste water. | |
Urban parking | Meters and fines (but much free business parking). | Meters and fines revenue was £9.28 million in 1995. |
Product charges: | ||
High hydrocarbon taxes. CO2 tax studied since 1991. | Mainly to raise revenue. Carbon taxes and permit trading due in 2004/5 | |
Admin./monitoring fees: | ||
Trade effluent | Fee, increasing to cover costs. | |
Integrated Pollution | Licence fee to firms. | To recover EPA costs. |
Tax differentiation: | ||
Leaded/unleaded petrol | Tax difference. | Unleaded sales rose from 7% in 1989, to over 60% by 1996. |
Vehicle Registration Tax | % of vehicle value, higher for vehicles > 2500 cc. | VRT revenue was £271 million in 1994. |
Annual road tax | Graded by engine cc. | Revenue was £249 million in 1994. |
Tax relief if scrapping 10-year-old car (now ended) | £1000 Vehicle Registration Tax relief. | Ran from 1.7.1995 to 31.12.1996. Cost is 20 % of VRT revenue. |
Exemption of VAT on public transport | Ticket sales are not charged VAT. | To reduce the price of public transport, possibly discourages adoption of new technology. |
Excise tax on diesel used by public transport is rebated | To reduce costs of public transport providers. | Discourages fuel efficiency and switching to cleaner fuels in public transport. |
Exemption from excise duty: waste oil | On processors of waste oil. | To encourage recycling. |
Urban renewal special tax rates: | 10 year Rates relief, double rent allowance and other reliefs. | Effective relief is high. |
Allowance for insurance bonds | Payments of insurance bonds for rehabilitation of mines is allowable against tax. | Cost to Exchequer is £1 million per year (1997) |
Subsidies: | ||
Food industry | Pollution control grants from EAGGF. | 8 to 10% of investment. |
Industry and commerce energy audit grant and efficiency grant | 40% up to £3000 for audit. Up to 40% to a value of £156 000 for investment (1997). | £2 million expenditure in first year, 1995. |
Rural Environment Protection Scheme REPS | Premium to farmers of £122/ha up to max 40 ha. Extra for Natural Heritage Areas (NHAs), Environmentally Sensitive Areas (ESAs) and organic farming. | Part of CAP reform: budget of £230 m over several years. To influence farming practice on small farms in its totality. |
Control of Farmyard Pollution Scheme (suspended) | Grants up to 60% to a value of £22 500 to small farms for slurry storage etc. | Under Operational Programme (OP) for Agriculture, Rural Development & Forestry. |
Afforestation grant | £1300 to £3000 per ha plus 20 year premium of £130 to £300 per ha (1997). | Part of CAP reform. Also OP grants for forestry improvement and amenity, of £500 to £3000. |
Explicit subsidy to public transport | Mainly to rail transport. | To reduce the price of public transport. |
Deposit refund schemes: | ||
Cans. | Isolated (e.g. Aran Islands) and very small scale. | |
Market creation: | ||
Government departments and agencies use recycled paper. |
Adapted by Sue Scott of the ESRI from an appendix to Chapter 2 in A. Barrett, J. Lawlor and S. Scott, The fiscal system and the polluter pays principle - a case study of Ireland. Ashgate, Aldershot, 1997
Endnotes
1. These emissions figures are all taken from the UNDP's 2004 Human Development Report. They differ slightly from the federal government's data.
2. Carbon Taxes: Which Households Gain or Lose? Environmental Protection Agency, PO Box 3000, Johnstown Castle, Co. Wexford, Ireland.
3. 'An Expensive Way to Combat Global Warming: Reform Needed in the EU Emissions Trading Regime', special article in the ESRI's Quarterly Economic Commentary, April, 2004. Can be downloaded from www.esri.ie/pdf/QEC0404_FitzGerald.pdf (PDF format)
4. Cf. Neumark, Fritz (1970): Grundsätze gerechter und ökonomisch rationaler Steuerpolitik. Tübingen: J.C.B. Mohr; Haller, Heinrich (1971): Die Steuern. Tübingen, J.C.B. Mohr, 2. Aufl.
5. Cf. Diefenbacher, Hans (2001): Gerechtigkeit und Nachhaltigkeit. Darmstadt: WBG, Kap. 4.
6. Cf. Streit, Manfred/Umbach, Dieter (1976): "Besteuerungsgrundsätze", in: diess. (Hrsg.): Die Wirtschaft heute. Mannheim: Bibliographisches Institut, 316ff.
7. Cf. Priewe, Jan (1998): Die öko-Steuer-Diskussion. Positionen und Kontroversen einer Bilanz. Berlin: edition sigma; Deutsches Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung Berlin/Finanzwissenschaftliches Forschungsinstitut an der Universität zu Köln (1999): Anforderungen an und Anknüpfungspunkte für eine Reform des Steuersystems unter ökologischen Aspekten. Berlin: Erich Schmidt Verlag; zum folgenden vgl. Reiche, Danyel /Krebs, Carsten (1999): Der Einstieg in die ökologische Steuerreform. Frankfurt u.a.: Peter Lang, 25ff.
8. On this see: Binswanger, Hans Christoph/Nutzinger, Hans G./Frisch, Heinz et al. (1983): Arbeit ohne Umweltzerstörung. Frankfurt: S. Fischer.
9. For overviews of the discussion of eco taxes so far see Reiche/Krebs (1999).
10. Cf. Positive Effekte der ökologischen Steuerreform, in: Umwelt, Heft 2, 2002, 94 97.
11. Cf. Bach, Stefan u.a. (2001a): Die ökologische Steuerreform in Deutschland. Eine modellgestützte Analyse ihrer Wirkungen auf Wirtschaft und Umwelt. Heidelberg: Physica Verlag; Bach, Stefan u.a. (2001b): Wirkungen der ökologischen Steuerreform in Deutschland, in: Wochenbericht des DIW, Heft 14, 220-225; Lutz, Christian/Meyer, Bernd (2001): Wirkungen der ökologischen Steuerreform auf Wirtschaft und Umwelt in Deutschland Ergebnisse von Simulationsrechnungen mit dem umweltökonomischen Modell PANTA RHEI. GWS Discussion Paper 2001/1. Osnabrück: Gesellschaft für Wirtschaftliche Strukturforschung.
12 Cf. BUND (o.J.; 2002): Eckpunkte zur Weiterentwicklung der ökologischen Steuerreform. o.O.: hekt. Manuskript.
13. Meyer, Bettina (1998): Sozialer Ausgleich erforderlich, in: Politische ökologie, Heft 56, 62-65.
14. See: Ministerium für Umwelt und Verkehr BadenWürttemberg (Hrsg.) (2001): Flexible Instrumente im Klimaschutz. Eine Anleitung für Unternehmen. Guidelines on CD-ROM or on the web at: http://www.isi.fhg.de.
15. See www.foes-ev.de/GBNnews3/2artikel4.html
16. Quote from: Wille, Joachim (2002): Der Streit über die Lizenz zum Klima-Vergiften, in: Frankfurter Rundschau, 26. January 2002, 9.
17. Interview mit BP-Vorstand Peter Knoedel über den Emissionshandel in dem ölkonzern, in: Frankfurter Rundschau vom 26. January 2002, 9.
18. See the calculation in the models PANTA RHEI und LEAN in Bach u.a. (2001b).
19. Cf. Bach u.a. (2001b), 222.
This paper is from Growth:The Celtic Cancer, the second Feasta Review. Copies of the Review can be ordered online from Green Books, priced at £9.95 plus postage and packaging. |
Continue to James Robertson's paper: Using common resources to solve problems